The Labor - Leisure Choice
The following was implemented in Maple by Marcus Davidsson (2009) davidsson_marcus@hotmail.com
and is based upon Kejak & Duras (2007) Preparatory macroeconomics
1) The Basic Labor-Leisure Model
1.1) The Derivation
We start by defining the following:
The total number of hours available is denoted by
The number of leisure hours is denoted by
The number of working hours is denoted by
The wage per hour is denoted by
We now note that if a person works
hours and the wage rate per hour is given by
then the income is given by
We now assume that the income from working
can be used to buy either consumption or leisure.
Our budget constraint can therefore be written as:
which says that the income from working must be equal to given by the cost of consumption where
is the price of consumption.
We now assume that the price of consumption is normalized to one so we get
which means that:
which can be written as:
Which can be written in an equal to zero form as:
 |
(1) |
which says that income from working
minus consumption must be equal to zero which means that the consumer always must run a
balanced budget ie he can not spend more money than he has earned from working.
We now assume that the consumer get utility from consumption
and leisure
. We assume that the utility function is simply
given by a constant return to scale Cobb Douglas utility function given by
 |
(2) |
which can be plotted as




The consumer now want to find the optimal amount of consumption and leisure that will maximize his utility.
We therefore set up the Lagrange as follows:
 |
(3) |
The first order conditions are given by
foc-1
 |
(4) |
we solve for
 |
(5) |
foc-2
 |
(6) |
we now add
on both sides so we get:
 |
(7) |
we divide both sides by
 |
(8) |
foc-3
 |
(9) |
which is equal to our initial budget constraint
Manipulation foc-1 and foc-2
foc-1 is given by
 |
(10) |
foc-2 is given by
 |
(11) |
We now set foc-1 equal to foc-2
 |
(12) |
we solve for
 |
(13) |
if we plug in the expression for c into our budget constraint we get:
 |
(14) |
We solve for
 |
(15) |
Which is the final expression for the optimal amount of leisure.
Since L was still present on the right hand side in our consumption equation we have to remove L by substituting in the expression for L
 |
(16) |
Which is the final expression for the optimal amount of consumption
1.2) Checking and Plotting the Model
We start by checking that we indeed have solved for the optimal values of leisure and consumption

















We now note that that our budget constraint is given by
 |
(18) |
We solve for
since we assume that consumption is located on the y-axis
 |
(19) |
We can now plot our budget constraint and the indifference curves
























2) The Basic Labor-Leisure Model with Labor Taxes
2.1) The Derivation
We again start by defining the following:
The total number of hours available is denoted by
The number of leisure hours is denoted by
The number of working hours is denoted by
The wage per hour is denoted by
The tax rate is denoted by
We now note that if a person works
hours and the wage rate per hour is given by
and the tax rate is given by
then the after tax income is given by:
We now assume that the after tax income from working
can be used to buy either consumption or leisure.
Our budget constraint can therefore be written as:
which says that the after tax income from working must be equal to given by the cost of consumption where
is the price of consumption.
We now assume that the price of consumption is normalized to one so we get
which means that:
which can be written as:
Which can be written in an equal to zero form as:
 |
(20) |
which says that the after tax income from working
minus consumption must be equal to zero which means that the
consumer always must run a balanced budget ie he can not spend more money than his after tax earnings from working.
We now assume that the consumer get utility from consumption
and leisure
. We assume that the utility function is simply
given by a constant return to scale Cobb Douglas utility function given by
 |
(21) |
which can be plotted as




The consumer now want to find the optimal amount of consumption and leisure that will maximize his utility.
We therefore set up the Lagrange as follows:
 |
(22) |
The first order conditions are given by
foc-1
 |
(23) |
we solve for
 |
(24) |
foc-2
 |
(25) |
we now add
on both sides so we get:
 |
(26) |
we divide both sides by
 |
(27) |
foc-3
 |
(28) |
which is equal to our initial budget constraint
Manipulation foc-1 and foc-2
foc-1 is given by
 |
(29) |
foc-2 is given by
 |
(30) |
We now set foc-1 equal to foc-2
 |
(31) |
we solve for
 |
(32) |
if we plug in the expression for C into our budget constraint we get:
 |
(33) |
We solve for
 |
(34) |
Which is the final expression for the optimal amount of leisure.
Since L was still present on the right hand side in our consumption equation we have to remove L by substituting in the expression for L
 |
(35) |
Which is the final expression for the optimal amount of consumption
2.2) Checking and Plotting the Model
We start by checking that we indeed have solved for the optimal values of leisure and consumption


















We now note that that our budget constraint is given by
 |
(37) |
We solve for
since we assume that consumption is located on the y-axis
 |
(38) |
We can now plot our budget constraint and the indifference curves with an Labor tax
































We can see that the optimal amount of consumption is decreasing when a labor tax is introduced but a labor tax does not affect the
optimal amount of leisure hours or working hours for that matter since
Legal Notice: ? Maplesoft, a division of Waterloo Maple Inc. 2009. Maplesoft and Maple are trademarks of Waterloo Maple Inc. Neither Maplesoft nor the authors are responsible for any errors contained within and are not liable for any damages resulting from the use of this material. This application is intended for non-commercial, non-profit use only. Contact the authors for permission if you wish to use this application in for-profit activities.